Notes on Corrupt Post-Communist Privatization
LAVINIA STAN
Undoubtedly, the
privatization of state-owned enterprises has received
the most attention of all components of the
post-communist economic restructuring unfolding in
Eastern Europe. Policy makers and commentators writing
on the subject have argued that state asset transfer to
foreign and domestic private hands is needed for
'objective' economic reasons related to improved
efficiency and productivity, the separation of political
and economic decisions, the introduction of hard budget
constraints and business practices consonant to market
demands, new capital influx and quicker adaptation to
consumer market demands. It was argued that the
cornerstone of a market economy is the presence of
clearly defined property rights, including possession of
the asset and the rights to use, derive income, exclude
others and exchange the asset. According to the economic
theory of post-communist, property rights are the
determinant of economic prosperity and a complete
re-socialization of economic actors, both private and
state-owned.
Few authors warning that
privatization could turn into a process dominated by
corruption and clientelism were taken seriously in the
early 1990s. Among these few was David Stark, who argued
in a seminal article that the Hungarian spontaneous
privatization process was moving the economy not from
plan to market but from plan to clan.1 Stark
claimed that instead of being a process that will take
care of itself once the appropriate institutional and
legal frameworks were set in place, privatization had to
be understood as a path-dependent and networks-focused
process. The strategic choice was "not between
clans or markets but of clans for markets." Yet
according to him, Hungary could still see the light at
the end of the tunnel with a "combination of direct
foreign investment and enough real private
entrepreneurs," since its particularistic networks
of enterprise directors and small-scale producers could
ultimately work as clans for market. I rely on the
metaphors of plan and clan to compare the starting
points, factors, processes and outcomes of
post-communist transformation in Hungary and Romania.
Focusing on clientelistic privatization and corruption
networks, and the governmental attempts to countervail
clandestine relationships, I suggest that whereas
Hungary benefited from its 'clans for market', the
Romanian clans endanger the functioning of the market
and, as in the Russian case, often prepare the
reemergence of 'clans for plan'.
Note that the ambiguity of the post-communist political
context made the privatization process a hotbed for
corruption and mismanagement. Instead of allowing new
domestic and foreign actors to enter the economy and
bring in capital and novel business practices,
privatization gave communist managers de jure
ownership rights over enterprises they already
controlled de facto. Instead of bringing revenue
to impoverished state budgets, privatization forced the
state to bail out unprofitable enterprises and allocate
important funds to wipe out the enormous arrears these
enterprises had accumulated over the years. Instead of
lifting the burden of bankrupt enterprises off the
state's shoulders or ending state subsidies to economic
agents that formally belong to the private sector,
privatization perpetuated them for reasons of national
interest or because of the protection these agents
enjoyed from high-ranking state officials. Instead of
granting ordinary citizens a stake in the economic
transition and the enterprises in which they had worked
for decades, some privatization methods excluded them in
favor of a handful of well-connected members of the
political and economic elite. Instead of bringing in
much needed competition that would benefit Eastern
European consumers, privatization often permitted the
establishment of large trusts integrating a multitude of
inter-connected firms and enjoying monopoly over
specific markets. In short, as Stark claimed, instead of
facilitating transition from plan to market,
privatization marked the transition from plan to clan.
Clearly, privatization has faced difficulties other than
corruption and clientelism. As documented, change in
ownership posed serious challenges that could not be
easily mitigated. Former Polish Minister of Property
Transformation Janusz Lewandowski referred to these
difficulties when remarking that "privatization is
when someone who doesn't know who the real owner is and
doesn't know what it's really worth sells something to
someone who doesn't have any money."2 A
decade after the start of the process, we know that
ownership rights transfer by itself could not produce a
well-functioning market economy. To make property rights
meaningful, post-communist societies need a regulatory
system for titles encouraging the lawful use of goods
and a criminal penalty severe enough to deter theft, two
conditions that Eastern European countries have yet to
fulfill. Unfortunately, few of the predictions
associated with the transition to a market economy did
materialize. Property rights were not clearly defined
though it would have been inexpensive to do so, the
fiscal system became predatory though rights enforcement
should have freed resources, and the state failed to
repress crime though it had more resources at its
disposal.3 While privatization was nurtured
by the belief that private enterprises are more
efficient than state-controlled monopolies, policy
makers apparently forgot that a free market without the
restraining rules of a civil society inevitably creates
opportunities for a great number of abuses.
This study must rest on a clear definition of
corruption. But deciding which that might be, proves a
difficult task, the more so since in post-communist
countries, corruption is not just misdemeanor described
by criminal legislation but an integral part of the
local culture, a widely accepted predisposition that
most Eastern Europeans do not take the time to question.
People live by rules that conflict systematically with
the norms written into laws largely because formal
systems fail to meet popular demands. Therefore, a
purely legalistic definition of corruption is
insufficient. Often the law does not define a category
of social actions and behaviors as corruption, but
focuses on subsets (bribery, graft, fraud, extortion,
office abuse, etc). Other times, it may not cover cases
publicly perceived as corrupt, and not infrequently it
can itself breed corruption. A process-oriented,
sociological definition would recognize the fact that
corruption implies agreement between social actors to
use resources they control in ways that are not
consonant with the interests of the people in general.
"A natural consequence of the use of power,"4
corruption is intimately linked with power mechanisms
and institutionalization, and with the idea of
subordinating the public interest to the rational
principle of maximizing private gains.5 Going
one step further, this study identifies clans as the
locus of corrupt practices that affected the
privatization process in Hungary and Romania.
Plan and Clan under
Communist Rule
All major characteristics associated with the
development of mafia-like clans were present before
1989: 1) an abdication of legitimate government power,
possibly encouraged by popular rejection of government's
authority, 2) excessive bureaucratic power, 3)
discretion and bureaucratic decisions that are unclear
and difficult to monitor and evaluate, and 4) financial
potential of illegal markets.6 In all
communist economies, networks served to integrate the
first and second economies. Inflexible political
hierarchies generated a demand for informal
intermediaries to sustain economic activities. Whenever
money did not work as an exchange medium, intermediaries
forged deals through personal connections according to
the principle 'favor for favor, commodity for
commodity'. Selective enforcement of laws, rules and
regulations governing economic conduct and selective use
of power enabled authorities to control informal corrupt
activity for their own purpose. Personal connections
were critical in accessing the nomenklatura ranks and in
securing access to the state resource distribution
system. Enrichment of high ranking party members was
common, as they managed public wealth and were the
source of power. Shortage of goods bred extra-legal
activity, virtually everyone having ties to the second
economy. Some of the parallel forms of material earnings
were direct results of scavenging the public wealth.
Gift offering and receiving became a habitual custom,
with its most prominent practitioners being party ranks.
Their concerted actions of enforcing and breaking the
system of rules influenced the level and distribution of
favoritisms. State enterprises managers had to befriend
those higher up to procure raw materials and supplies,
thus developing a "network of cozy relations among
economic managers and their bureaucrats."7
Long tenure periods permitted party officials and
enterprise managers to create fiefdoms and dynastic
clans dominated by personal ties, overlapping
membership, and patron-client relations. These clans
were particularistic networks of trust and reliability,
cohesive, dense and tightly intertwined, hierarchical
and non-transparent. Within clans, exchange was
vertical, obligations were asymmetric, and secretive
honor codes facilitated cooperation among clan members.
Each clan shared its own values, enforced its own
behavioral norms, maintained strong intra-group
solidarity and guarded barriers to entry. Clans were
held together by informal, personal ties and family
relations, but also by formal ties of authority
subordinating weak clients to powerful patrons.
Defending and promoting insiders, clans stifled
outsiders, limiting their options and increasing entry
costs into the second economy. While clans did exhibit
forms of social capital, that capital did not go beyond
the tight circle of clan members. Instead of breeding
networks of trust and solidarity at the level of the
general society, the communist-era clans rested on the
'amoral familistic' inter-personal relations
characteristic of Southern Europe.
During communism, clans had to reckon with the
restrictions imposed by the plan. Command economies were
based on five-year plans of economic development,
outlined by central agencies and enforced by political
leadership through direct state control. The logic of
communist development, and the desire to outperform the
capitalist world, led to the imposition of ever higher
plan targets which in late communism became impossible
to reach by most economic actors. As a result, managers
and bureaucrats misrepresented data, and did not shy
away from reporting inflated results. The chain of lies
and corruption stretched from high-level apparatchiks,
responsible for making bureaucratic appointments, to
low-level civil servants. Note, however, that planning
was neither fully enforceable nor comprehensible. Plan
revisions and bargaining between enterprise directors
and central planners were common practices that followed
market logic but were constrained by bureaucrats and the
legal system. But while it partially corrected for the
rigidity of the communist economic system, the second
economy blurred the lines of responsibility and
accountability. Under communism, enterprise managers
acquired the right to use, and to profit from,
enterprises and could "supplement their individual
wealth by hiding profits and skimming extra
production."8 Many opportunities to
organize informally and covertly existed for small
groups of high ranking administrators and enterprise
managers in export-oriented companies and specific
industries.
Of all Eastern European communist states, Hungary went
the furthest in allowing legalized second-economy
activity. Household farming was recognized as part of
the private sector, though it remained technically
dependent on the state. The Hungarian communist regime
favored enterprise autonomy, instructed enterprises to
maximize profits, and encouraged people to find extra
employment. Under gulash communism, the second economy
helped individuals meet their needs and acted as social
mollifier. After the 1968 New Economic Mechanism,
economic life was largely depoliticized and informal
economic activities were widely tolerated. The 'social
contract' binding the regime to its people accepted
economic prosperity in exchange for preservation of the
political status quo. In contrast, Ceausescu's brand of
communism was driven more by dogmatic ideology and less
by economic concerns, and rejected the mixed character
of gulash communism. The informal economy helped
circumvent supply bottlenecks in a rigid command
economy, but was considered to represent a direct threat
to state regulatory powers. Officials, for whom private
entrepreneurship represented a parasitic bourgeois
attitude antagonistic to the building of socialism,
strove to limit the second economy as much as possible.
Less flexible, tolerant or pragmatic than Hungarians,
the Romanian communist officials mythologized plan,
suppressed the market and neglected public needs and
interests, sowing the seeds of public dissatisfaction
and future confrontation with the elite. Fearful for his
control of the country, Ceausescu frequently rotated
party cadres and marginalized those who could be
regarded as his potential successors or who directly
opposed him. Cadre rotation did not affect members of
Ceausescu's family, who towered unchallenged over the
Romanian society. Disdain for the mad dictator united
his silent opponents within the party. These sympathies
were to form the basis of post-communist clans gathering
former apparatchiks.
Clans in Post-Communist
Times
After the collapse of state-controlled economies, the
mixture of formal and informal networks saved Hungarian
and Romanian societies from total breakdown. The
deterioration of the bureaucracy-run economy devalued
formal network endowments in favor of the informal
endowments in attaining wealth and power. Networking
became even more crucial in the post-communist period
given the manifold uncertainties and hardships of
transition. New pressures bolstered personal networks as
a means of coping with difficulties and grabbing new
opportunities. The persistence of unofficial bargaining
resulted in the further ascension of clans as informal,
particularistic, extra-legal and non-transparent
entities. Building on older particularistic groupings,
closed clans of interconnected politicians,
industrialists, bankers, media figures, consultants and
private security forces emerged. Pursuing expansion,
these clans practiced the politics of exclusion, seeking
to protect and promote the gains and interests of their
members while at the same time suppressing competition
and blocking new entrants to the market. They were
propped up, among other things, by uncertain property
rights, underdeveloped legal system, poor investment
conditions, public distrust and political instability.
Privatization had significant implications for clans,
but transition could not end corruption. In both
countries the privatization process began spontaneously.
At the start of the reform process more pragmatically
minded members of the outgoing communist administration
and enterprise managers (the so-called directocracy)
took advantage of their privileged positions and became
the primary property-owners, lobbying in favor of
privatization models allowing managers and workers to
purchase shares and greatly resisting models seeking to
separate management from ownership. Some directors were
content to have ownership dispersed among enterprises
workers as long as workers' collectives agreed not to
interfere with management in exchange for job security.
Other managers acquired a controlling block of shares
through a variety of manipulative schemes directed
against their own workers. As a result, well-positioned
and well-connected insiders acquired most of the state
properties gratis, converting their previous
politically-based status into economic power and taking
advantage of the fact that newly created firms had not
had the time to overcome the difficulties of collective
action. This meant that "lobbying power . . . iwass
held disproportionately by those enterprises that need
to be replaced by new or foreign firms."9
Stark makes the important observation that in
Hungary the political vacuum of 1989 was not a legal
vacuum, while the negotiated transition of political
power was not a negotiated transition of economic power
because the roundtable negotiations were not attended by
key economic players - enterprise managers, trade
unions, workers' councils. Unbound by the outcomes of
roundtable discussions, managers and bureaucrats, who
entered transition as the strongest organized group,
decided to move unilaterally and with unparalleled
independence. Spontaneous privatization allowed
enterprise managers to choose their own owners, and the
elite of the party-state apparatus to take advantage of
the transformation process. In these nomenklatura
buy-outs, apparatchiks with no prior industrial
experience or expertise in production or marketing
bailed out into profitable ventures.
Spontaneous privatization thus became related to illicit
or improper gains (transfer of wealth by stealth) giving
rise to ambiguous structures characterized by the
blurred boundaries of public and private, the fluid
boundaries among enterprises, and discretionary asset
and liability distribution. In both countries, the
volume of assets privatized through the "rape of
the state" was reportedly enormous, though nowhere
it can be accurately estimated. As spontaneous
privatization took place informally, through the blatant
theft of state assets and diversion of revenues from
state enterprises, it represented the very essence of
extra-legal activities, a continuation of the corrupt
practices that flourished under communism. Many of the
new entrepreneurs were nomenklatura members with a long
experience of suppliers in the secondary economy. By
making them important capital owners, spontaneous
privatization allowed them to preserve a hold on
economic resources while giving them freedom
unimaginable during the old regime. To accomplish their
economic interests, some of these managers and
bureaucrats turned to politics to influence the
political resources of the system and to exert pressure
on political outcomes (usually by opposing rapid
reforms). They were uninterested in serious economic and
administrative reforms because they profited handsomely
from plundering the state. Seeking market domination,
they continuously forged alliances - both horizontal
(local) and vertical.
This uncontrolled and inequitable distribution of public
resources weakened the state and incited public outrage.
Both Romanian and Hungarian authorities reacted by
introducing official privatization programs. In Hungary,
a public offering of shares, competitive tenders and
employee-share ownership programs were introduced, but
soon it became clear that they were doomed to failure
due to the enterprise managers' reluctance to aid the
programs. Adopting a realistic stance, the Hungarian
government admitted defeat and agreed to the
self-privatization of small- and medium-sized
enterprises. This modified version of spontaneous
privatization was implemented under the supervision of
the State Privatization Agency, and it enriched both
former managers and privatization officials. In contrast
to Hungarian pragmatism, Romanian privatization was
colored by blatant populism. In the mass privatization
program, citizens received vouchers, but failed to
acquire any tangible assets as a result. Only
well-connected and well-informed individuals could
obtain attractive pieces of state property through
accumulating large blocks of vouchers. Excluded from the
voucher privatization program were the most important
and profitable export-oriented industries, whose fate
was arbitrarily decided behind close doors by a circle
of top politicians, bankers, industrialists and the
State Ownership Fund. Special laws for special cases
favored bidders with better access to top politicians
and their entourage, rather than bidders offering best
price or bidders with most potential to redress the
failing enterprises.
Despite divergent official privatization scenarios, in
both Hungary and Romania inside information, insider
lending, and insider privatization were the key tools
for the distribution of state property. Under the
patronage of the political architects of privatization,
the most valuable resources were channeled to their own
select clients. In Hungary, the already existing limited
private ownership needed formalization. Pilfering was
permissible if it allowed national asset reproduction or
if it gave political elites a chance to have their own
feast.10 But the key difference was the fact
that by favoring property de-concentration through
breaking up large companies into smaller ones, Hungarian
reforms stimulated competition and attracted outside
capital. Hungary's relative openness was related to the
fact that the country could not succeed without foreign
investment, but also to the fact that economic
pragmatism was combined with the society-wide
intellectual and moral desire to Westernize
institutionally and be recognized as part of Europe.
During privatization, foreigners acquired shares of
strategic companies in the oil, gas, telecommunications
and electric industries. The country attracted over
one-third of all foreign direct investment in the former
communist block, hence every Hungarian aspiring to
become rich had to rely on international networks.
Operating on commercial grounds and relatively
disengaged from the pre-existing personal networks in
the country, foreign capital played an anti-clandestine
role in Hungary.
By contrast, the Romanian economy was much more
monopolized, and the country's choice of privatization
methods allowed for the survival of the fattest, instead
of the fittest, producing financial empires unable to
sense market changes. Reliance on powerful political
patrons remained indispensable to beat the country's
notorious red-tape. Instead of welcoming it, the first
three Romanian governments confronted foreign capital, a
stand supported by special interest groups wishing to
keep the national economy under domestic control.
Exploiting the advantages of national monopolies, the
Romanian elite managed to protect the communist legacy
of a closed economy in an increasingly open world
market. Theft on a grand scale was possible because the
communist elite maintained its hold on the state. Around
75 percent of Romanian nouveaux riches were members of
the nomanklatura or the secret police.11
Nationalist sentiment translated into a false perception
of a nation's self-sufficiency, while national
self-closure was orchestrated by domestic
financial-political clans that could preserve their
power only by remaining exclusive. The clans did admit
friendly foreigners, but only under conditions of close
supervision. A strong distinction between those who
belong and those who do not belong has endured during
transition. Romania also lacked foreign capital as a
benign vehicle for profitability and efficiency.
Foreigners on the fringes of Romanian clans have been
too weak to promote a strategy of clans for market.
In the country, much opposition to broadly-based
privatization came from enterprise managers because they
stood to lose their job and personal comfort and social
position. Delayed privatization allowed them to develop
their own businesses, thus benefiting a handful of
people and impoverished the public property and every
taxpayer. Former party ranks, while continuing to hold
key positions, transferred funds and goods from state
enterprises to their private companies through the
formation of affiliated limited companies. By virtue of
their positions, these individuals constantly bribed
departmental directors, ministers and members of
Parliament to have reservations on quick economic
liberalization and to maintain state subsidies to
unprofitable enterprises. The Romanian business sector
is both overregulated (in the number of stamps and
approvals required for every franchise) and
under-regulated (in the lack of protection for consumer
or honest firms) as a result of these corrupt practices.
Though Law 58/1991 allowed for a variety of
privatization methods, up to 1995 medium-sized
enterprises and small establishments were sold or given
away to insiders often with payment accepted in the form
of vouchers or deferred payment arrangements, in order
to solve the problem of a lack of capital in the
purchasers. The process occurred at a snail pace, lacked
transparency, left discretionary power to high level
officials, and bred high levels of corruption.
While in both countries upper nomenklatura echelons were
partly dismantled, Hungary's political context has been
less inviting to corruption than Romania's. Hungarian
civil society was more influential and successful in
imposing limits on the range of actions at the disposal
of government officials. By contrast, civil society in
Romania started to organize itself only after the demise
of communism. The separation of powers was clearer than
in Romania where the judiciary, the real bastion of
nomenklatura, remains the most corrupt branch of power.
In Romania the notions of trust and credibility remain
vague, and both winners and losers of reforms could only
depend on networks as a tested trust and support system
for copping and grabbing. Hungarian and Romanian
networks also differ in terms of their potential for
learning and change. A resolute and continuous market
building in Hungary contrasted a hesitant "one step
forward, two steps back" development in Romania.
Consequently, the trajectory "clans for
markets" pursued in Hungary meant a metamorphosis
of clan networks into less rigid, loosely coupled
networks guided primarily by market-style instrumental
rationality rather than value rationality. Though less
cohesive, these networks are more adaptable and
effective in the pursuit of marketization. In Romania,
however, deep distrust of the impartial hand of the
market has reinforced heavy reliance on the visible hand
of the state and high-ranking patrons as the facilitator
of actions and the protector from formal demands. The
resilience of communist-era hierarchical, closed and
ambiguous structures in Romania has been the outcome of
both resistance to market rationality in the interest of
preserving previous monopolies and the backlash against
a poorly implemented, painful transition that seemed to
go nowhere.
Conclusion
The literature is contradictory as to the
relationship between corruption and economic
development. Respected scholars see corruption as
facilitating economic modernization and benefiting
democracy. Huntington, for example, argues that
corruption is indirect participation in the
decision-making process, highly functional during early
modernization or rapid socioeconomic change.
Occasionally, corruption may even raise economic growth.
Leff opined that at first "speed money" may
enable individuals to avoid bureaucratic delay, while
later public servants may work harder because bribes
serve as rate compensations. Corrupt practices may thus
provide practical solutions to social problems, and
their potentially negative consequences are overcome by
their public benefits: economic development and capital
formation, national integration through consensus
between leaders and masses, and increased governmental
capacity to legitimize newly created institutions.12
More recent studies relate corruption to economic
backwardness, and argue that "speed money" may
increase transaction efficiency only in countries where
government officials artificially create delays in order
to be bribed by imposing excruciatingly cumbersome
bureaucratic regulations.13 Other studies
argue that corruption prospers if market competition is
weak, since a few firms collude more easily. Then, once
firms have learned to collude, they are able to more
efficiently bribe politicians and public officials to
avoid antitrust enforcement, obtain favorable
legislation, and rig public contracts."14
But the literature is more unanimous in its
assessment that corruption impedes marketization. Among
the first to tackle the intricacies of corruption in
post-communist Eastern Europe, Holmes identified a
panoply of processes whereby particularistic interests
appropriate state resources at the expense of the larger
society. More recently, Rose-Ackerman suggested that,
with the exception of over-bureaucratized states,
corruption can never help build and sustain the dual
political and economic transition in Eastern Europe.15
Building on Putnam's study of Italy but discussing the
case of post-communist Russia, Stoner-Weiss concluded
that in the short run corruption and clientelism might
help regions overcome their problems of common action by
oiling both commerce and bureaucracy, but that in the
long run that advantage would prove to be only apparent
as in those regions economic clans would ultimately work
for their own benefit rather than that of the larger
community.16 Stark anticipated this insight
when arguing that the key to successful marketization
are clans capable of nurturing the civic spirit akin to
democracy and building cohesive networks of trust,
cooperation and stable subcontracting that made possible
the Japanese miracle. The focus, according to these
authors, should be on the kind of norms, values and
relationships developed within the major groups
participating in the economy. The feelings of
cooperation and solidarity that tie friends and business
partners together should be carried out of the group
into the larger community for economic benefits to be
reaped. If not, the group resembles more a clan that, by
always looking for its immediate interest and assuming
that the others are doing, will reject cooperation with
outsiders.17
Twelve years after the collapse of communism, and
as many years since the launching of post-communist
transition, the general feeling among those studying
Eastern European politics, as well as among those
practicing it, is one of dissatisfaction for not having
taken seriously early warnings that the prescribed
recipe of economic transformation might lead not to a
successful marketization of the Japanese type but to an
economic hybrid combining monopolistic remnants of
communist era with Southern European mafia-like clans.
Rather than accepting one single blueprint of transition
for all Eastern European countries, we should have
strived to find different medicine for countries of
different background and economic potential. Hungary's
gulash communism allowed for the emergence of a second
economy that would later generate both potential buyers
and a significant source of capital for the
privatization process. Romania's Stalinist authorities
suppressed the second economy. Other things being equal,
some privatization methods are more likely to breed
corruption, and the same method might lead to different
economic configurations in different countries.
NOTES
1 David Stark, "Privatization in
Hungary: From Plan to Market or From Plan to
Clan?," East European Politics and Societies
vol. 4, no. 3 (Fall 1990), pp. 351-392.
2 K. Verdery, What Was Socialism and What
Comes Next? (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 1996), p. 210.
3 Frederico Varese, "The Transition to
the Market and Corruption in Post-Socialist
Russia," in Political Corruption, ed. by
Paul Heywood (Oxford: Blackwell, 1997), pp. 163-180.
4 Andras Sajo, "Corruption, Clientelism
and the Future of the Constitutional State in Eastern
Europe", East European Constitutional Review (Spring
1998), pp. 37-46, here p. 41.
5 J. S. Nye, "Corruption and Political
Development: A Cost-Benefit Analysis," American
Political Science Review vol. 61, no. 2 (1967), p.
419.
6 Annelise Anderson, "The Red Mafia. A
Legacy of Communism," in Economic Reform in
Russia, ed. By Edward Lazear (Stanford, CA: Hoover
Institution Press, 1994).
7 Verdery, What Was Socialism, p. 22.
8 M. McFaul, "The allocation of property
rights in Russia: the first round," Communist
and Post-Communist Studies vol. 29, no. 3 (1996),
pp. 287-308, here 291.
9 M. Olson, "Why the transition from
communism is so difficult?," Eastern Economic
Journal vol. 21 no. 4 (1995), pp. 437-461, here
458-9.
10 Jozsef Torgyan, leader of the
Smallholders' Party part of the Hungarian coalition
government, displayed nepotism; members of his family
held high-level positions in Malev airlines, OTP Travel
(exclusive travel organizer of Torgyan's Ministry of
Agriculture and Rural Development) and Szerencsejarek
Rt. (a state-owned company controlling lotteries and
gambling in Hungary).
11 Alin Ceobanu, When Socialism Meets
Capitalism: Corrupt Practices and Post-Communist
Transition. A Comparative Analysis (University of
Nebraska, MA thesis, 1998.
12 Nathaniel Leff, "Economic Development
through Bureaucratic Corruption," American
Behavioral Scientist vol. 8, no. 3 (1964), pp. 8-14.
13 Susan Rose-Ackerman, "Democracy and
Grand Corruption," International Social Science
Journal vol. 48 (1996), pp. 360-380 and Corruption: A
Study in Political Economy (New York: Academic
Press, 1978), Michael Johnson, "The Search for
Definitions: The Vitality of Politics and the Issue of
Corruption", International Social Science
Journal vol. 48 (1996), pp. 320-335 and
"Corruption and Political Culture in Britain and
the United States," Polity vol. 18 (1989), pp.
367-391, Serguey Braguinsky, "Corruption and
Schumpeterian Growth in Different Economic
Environments", Contemporary Economic Policy vol.
14 (1996), pp. 14-25, Paolo Mauro, "Corruption and
Growth", Quarterly Journal of Economics vol.
109 (1995), pp. 681-712, and Andrei Shleifer and Robert
Vishny, "corruption", Quarterly Journal of
Economics vol. 108 (1993), pp. 559-617.
14 Varese, "The Transition to the
Market," p. 170.
15 Rose-Ackerman, Corruption: A Study in
Political Economy.
16 Robert Putnam, Making Democracy Work.
Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1996) and Katherine
Stoner-Weiss, Local Heroes: The Political Economy of
Russian Regional Governance (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1997).
17 Daniel Kaufmann and Paul Siegelbaum,
"Privatization and Corruption in Transition
Economies", Journal of International Affairs
vol. 50 (1996), pp. 419-458.
LAVINIA STAN - Dr.,
Director al "Centrului pentru Studii
Post-Comuniste", St. Francis Xavier University,
Canada.
sus
|